market makers

As ideological battles are waged over the benefits of free markets, the challenges of financial regulation, the inefficiency of policymaking, and the design of a sustainable path forward, pundits often attack one another without a fundamental understanding of the mechanics of our modern financial system. This primer helps to explain the unique roles that banks and capital markets play in the efficient (and sometimes painfully inefficient) functioning of of modern society. While it won’t settle any debates, it certainly reminds us how little we may know about the way the economy works…


Did the Capital Markets Fail Us?
By Karen Johnson | Thursday, March 25, 2010

Amid the debate about excessive bonuses and inadequate risk management, it is useful to ask why the faith that the United States put into the ability of capital markets (in comparison to traditional banks) to deliver good outcomes now seems unjustified. Did the capital markets fail us? If so, why and how? Karen Johnson explores.

As we seek to strengthen the pace of macroeconomic recovery from the financial crisis of 2007/2009, the debate rages on as to how to proceed to reform the U.S. financial sector so that the odds of such a crisis occurring again are as low as possible.

The job of the financial system is to mobilize the savings of all in the economy and to allocate that financial capital well in an uncertain world. From the perspective of savers, financial institutions enable the pooling of risk, often in complex ways, and at the same time provide maturity transformation as well as liquidity transformation.

Capital markets are not well-suited to do all the financial intermediation in the economy.

While maturity transformation serves the purpose of allowing claims held by savers to have shorter maturities than do the underlying assets held by financial firms or the physical assets in the economy, liquidity transformation helps savers to hold small amounts of various claims available for purchase or sale with low transactions costs.

Everyone benefits from the resulting ability of the economy to finance investment in real capital that at times involves projects that are large in scale, indivisible and take considerable time to yield a return.

Given this somewhat simplified picture of the tasks of a financial system, why do we have both banks — deposit-taking institutions that negotiate individual loans on idiosyncratic terms with borrowers — and capital markets (all other financial entities)?

Capital markets, in contrast to banks, require standardization of the obligations of the borrowers. These obligations, referred to as securities, are traded in an organized fashion, perhaps on an exchange.

Such trading requires that pricing be straightforward and that all the information required by a potential buyer of the security is provided cheaply and quickly. For ongoing trading in the security to occur, the terms of a given security must be standardized, i.e., many holders but a common set of terms.

In the U.S. financial system, the horizon for decision-making shortened as the focus became one of trading rather than holding to maturity.

Such secondary trading is usually anonymous. Savers sell such securities among themselves without any reason for the buyer of a block of securities, say bonds or equity of firm X, to care who the seller happens to be. But the buyer does need to know exactly what value is promised by the security and by whom so that he can judge whether to buy and can be confident that a future buyer could also do so.

Capital markets have developed various ways of providing the information needed by potential buyers, such as listing requirements on stock exchanges for public companies and ratings provided by rating agencies.

Clearly, on the lending side, banks face information costs that are large, as they need to evaluate the potential for repayment of each loan and for the associated project to prove profitable. And bank managers need to build into loan contracts some forward-looking protection and to monitor creditworthiness of the borrower over time.

This need for costly information can be a reason that a given bank office has a limited ability to serve a wide geographical area — the farther away are potential borrowers, the higher information costs may be. These same factors may limit the size that a bank in a given community might be able to be to function effectively.

Together these considerations might limit how well such a bank can diversify its loan portfolio, lessening the efficiency with which the bank allocates available funds and limiting its ability to minimize risk.

Because leverage is generally much greater in capital markets than it is in banking, it must be addressed as an issue, perhaps by regulation.

Cost and information barriers suggest that on the lending side, banks operate in separate or partly separate markets defined by community and geography, resulting in possible limits to competition among community banks. Hence capital markets offer lower cost and more efficient allocation where they are feasible.

Some of that lower cost on capital markets reduces the interest charged to borrowers, and some takes the form of higher returns for lenders.

In the years before the recent financial crisis, the introduction and development of asset securitization provided a mechanism for allowing banking to become more capital-market-like. Banks became originators of loans that they then sold — the so-called originate and distribute model.

Banks could use their information-processing abilities to originate loans, but by selling these loans into the capital markets they no longer faced geographical concentration or other diversification-limiting characteristics in their asset portfolios. Banks substituted fee income from the loan origination for the interest earned on long-term loans.

By passing on their loans to other investors and by accessing the capital markets for funds themselves, banks could originate loans in a volume not limited by their deposits. How did the buyers of these loans avoid the information cost burdens that idiosyncratic lending implies? They bundled many loans together and sold the resulting securities — substituting diversification for the absent information.

Banks’ perspective now was not what would be the long-term income flow to them of a given loan — but what would be the price at which they could soon sell the loan.

Banks’ perspective changed from what would be the long-term income flow to them of a given loan to what would be the price at which they could soon sell the loan.

In addition to the diversification offered by a security that had components from many borrowers, investors looked to rating agencies and continuous market trading to help them value any given security.

Securitization thus forged links between banking and capital markets. It broke down the differences in forms of financial intermediation that had characterized markets previously, especially in the United States, where regulation had put commercial banking in a separate category. Changes in regulation enhanced this process.

As a result, U.S. financial markets became even more unified and national — further reducing some persistent inefficiencies. Securitization was an important and useful innovation. However, capital markets are not well-suited to do all the financial intermediation in the economy.

Past mistakes

These developments changed the overall nature of the financial intermediation process in U.S. financial markets:

# The balance of bank-type activity versus capital-market-type activity swung in the direction of capital-market activity. Taken as a whole, the system took on more of the characteristics of capital markets. Banks became more exposed to events on capital markets.

# On average in the financial system, the horizon for decision-making shortened. The focus became one of trading rather than holding to maturity. Attention to long-run ability to repay was diminished.

# Access to borrowing was expanded most for less-credit-worthy borrowers — borrowers where idiosyncratic information and risk management might be thought to be most important. Non-investment-grade firms and households falling into sub-prime categories were able to borrow more freely than before because the risk characteristics of a bundle of loans to many such borrowers were stronger than those of a loan to any one of them.

# Risk analysis focused on the expected correlation among assets bundled into a security and among the various securitized assets held in a portfolio. But investors lost sight of the fact that such correlations depend on the shock in question. Mortgages spread across the country might be uncorrelated with respect to a shock to a given industry or region — but highly correlated with respect to a shock to investors’ risk preference.

Suggestions for reform

Little was done in our approach to U.S. financial market regulation as these changes unfolded. Now that we have experienced a severe crisis throughout our financial system, what should we do as we proceed toward reform?

# Because of the greater role of capital markets relative to banking, we need to think more about safety and soundness for capital markets. The information that must be transparent in annual reports and other sources for potential investors should be expanded and monitored. It is essential that a mechanism for winding down a participant in the capital markets in the event of bankruptcy in a way that does not have huge negative impacts on other participants and on the functioning of markets be established.

# Regulation needs to be framed in a way that recognizes the limits of diversification to diminish risk and that limits the complexity of any traded securitized product. Because leverage is generally much greater in capital markets than it is in banking, the overall increase in leverage in the financial system must be addressed, perhaps by regulation.

# The shorter horizon inherent in capital market trading must be countered. One possible way would be to limit the fraction of any loan obligation of a given borrower that may be securitized — and so bundled with loans of other borrowers. The resulting residual portion of the loan could be mandated to be held by the originator or, at least, could be eligible for trading only as a simple security that involved no other borrower.

These steps will not resolve all problems on the financial markets, but they are moves in the direction of thinking about the consequences of the greater integration of banking and capital markets that has, in fact, already occurred.